Volume 2, Number 1, 2015, Y16–Y25 journal homepage: region.ersa.org

Concentration of resources and economic development: An empirical overview*

David Castells-Quintana1
1 AQR-IREA, Universidad de Barcelona, Barcelona 08034, Spain E-mail: dcastells@ub.edu Received: 16 April 2015/Accepted: 22 April 2015

*I want to express my gratitude to all of those with whom I have discussed the ideas presented here, which has allowed me to improve the research summarised in this letter. In particular, I want to thank Vicente Royuela for all his help. I also thank Vassilis Tselios for his comments and suggestions.

Abstract. This paper summarizes the main results and contributions from my Ph.D. dissertation on the concentration of resources and economic development. Its empirical analysis, summarised here, focuses on two major world trends in modern economic development: increasing agglomeration and rising inequalities. The impact of both trends on long-run economic growth is studied, and results are discussed in light of relevant policy debates.

Key words: concentration, inequality, agglomeration, growth, development

JEL classification: O1, O4, R1

1 Introduction

World trends over the last few decades point to two clear traits in economic growth: increasing geographic concentration of economic activity (i.e. agglomeration) and rising inequality within countries. The co-evolution of both trends is a great challenge for sustainable economic development. Inevitably, these realities attracted, and continue to attract substantial research to understand and address these phenomena. Nonetheless, important gaps remain. This paper seeks to summarize the main results and contributions from my Ph.D. dissertation, where trends of agglomeration and inequality, and their impact on long-run economic growth were studied.1

1.1 Increasing agglomeration and rising inequalities

Urbanisation is increasing globally, resulting in ever-larger agglomerations. The World Bank’s data shows that while in 1960 nearly one-third of the world population lived in cities, in 2010 this figure was above 50% and was steadily growing by 1% every three years. At this rate, by 2050 nearly two-thirds of the world’s population will be living in cities, with one out of two urban inhabitants living in cities of more than 1 million inhabitants. Furthermore, among the “million plus” cities, those megacities with at least ten million inhabitants will experience the largest percentage increase. Along with record changes in urbanization, income inequality has reached historically high levels. According to Milanovic (2012), using data on household surveys, individual global inequality increased from a Gini index of 68.4 in 1998 to 70.7 in 2005. According to his results, while most differences in global income still depend on location, the recent increases in global inequality are largely attributable to increases in inequality within countries.

Increasing agglomeration and rising inequalities are not independent of each other, nor are they neutral in the process of development. The UN Habitat’s State of the World’s Cities 2008/2009 Report found that disparities within cities, and between cities and regions within the same country are growing. Additionally, the report finds that despite the notion that economic growth is often accompanied by rising inequalities (see also Ravallion 2009), cities with high levels of inequality generally experience reduced economic growth. As cities grow and intra-urban inequalities increase, ‘informal settlements’ or slums also tend to grow. According to UN-Habitat, approximately one billion people – one in every seven people on the planet – live in urban slums. Growing at high rates (e.g. higher than 4.5 per cent per annum in Sub-Saharan Africa), slums are expected to host two billion inhabitants by 2030.

2 Concentration of resources and economic development, a brief literature review

Agglomeration and inequality represent the spatial and social dimensions, respectively, of the concentration of resources that occurs as countries develop. The former is related to the geographical concentration of economic activity and the population; and the latter to the concentration of income and wealth across individuals. Classical theories of economic development describe the process of development as one of structural change associated with a concentration of resources (Lewis 1954Kaldor 1961). These theories describe economic growth in the early stages of development as fueled by rural-urban migration and an economic transformation from agricultural-based activities, performing under decreasing or constant returns to scale, to industrial-based ones, performing under increasing returns resultant from the positive externalities of proximity. This process of structural change is associated with the geographical concentration of economic activity and the population (Williamson 1965Hansen 1990Henderson 2003), increased inequalities (Kuznets 1955), and possibilities for high urban unemployment (Todaro 1969), which can lead to a rise in slums (Rauch 1993). The evolution of the geographical concentration of economic activity and of inequality however, is more complex than in classical models. Furthermore, the factors involved in this evolution are not always associated with economic growth. Geographical concentration can be driven by the exhaustion of resources in the rural sector, deteriorating climatic conditions, or conflict. Income inequality can be the outcome of a particular set of endowments, deficient institutions, and/or a lack of equal opportunities. And there exist benefits as well as costs – in terms of economic efficiency – that are associated with both spatial and social concentration. Current trends in these two dimensions of concentration, and the trade-off between their respective benefits and costs, have attracted substantial research in recent years.

On the one hand there is a growing interest for studying the role of spatial issues on economic development, both at a regional as well as national level. These issues are approached from the fields of economic geography and urban economics. One particular aspect that has attracted special attention is the effect of agglomeration economies on economic growth and their effect on spatial disparities, for which an extensive theoretical and empirical literature already exists.2 Benefits from agglomeration are expected, as geographical proximity allows for positive externalities (i.e. from knowledge spillovers), which increase productivity and therefore allow for higher growth. But costs are also expected from mechanisms such as growth-deterring congestion, which results in high rents, high transport costs and increased pollution.

On the other hand, in the field of economic development there is renewed interest in the relationship between inequalities and economic growth as a relevant aspect of the development process. While classical theories describe the positive relationship between inequality and capital accumulation as necessary for growth, especially at the early stages of development and in particular in the presence of capital markets’ imperfections, modern theories highlight the mechanisms through which inequality negatively affects economic growth. These are, broadly, related to lower human capital accumulation, distortive and extractive economic policies, social unrest and conflict, lower aggregate demand and higher fertility rates.3

3 Methodology and data

The research synthesized in this paper relies on neoclassical models of economic growth to estimate cross-country regressions of long-run economic growth, using cross-section, and dynamic and static panel data models. The results presented here rely on estimations techniques using instrumental variables in order to identify causal effects: They include System GMM, Two Stage Residual Inclusion, and panel Fixed Effects-Instrumental Variables.4 The majority of the data is at the national level, with some measured at the urban or city level, always with the aim of cross-country comparisons. The time span under analysis covers 1960 to 2010, with variations in range depending on the specific estimation. The dependent variable is long-run economic growth, measured over 5, 10 or 37 years, depending on the question under analysis and the robustness of the results. The key independent variables are income inequality and various measures for agglomeration, both of which are measured at the national level.

The analysis carried out is divided into three main empirical studies. The first takes a broader perspective incorporating the evolution of the three key variables under study – inequalities, agglomeration and economic growth. The second focuses on the inequality-growth relationship. The third looks at the effect of urban concentration on economic growth. The next section presents the primary findings of each of these studies.

4 Main results

4.1 Concentration of resources and economic development

The first empirical analysis5 studies the joint impact of increasing urbanisation, urban concentration, and inequality on economic growth, from both a descriptive and an econometric analysis for a sample of 51 countries around the world using panel data from 1970 to 2007. Growth is regressed on several controls, agglomeration, and inequality measures. Variations in magnitude and changes over time, as well as the interaction between the two, are included:

yit =   α(yi,t-1)+ β1(Ai,t-1)+ β2(Ii,t-1)+ β3(ΔAi,t-1)+ β4(ΔIi,t- 1) +
        β5(ΔAi,t-1)(ΔIi,t-1)+ (X )γ + ui,t                            (1)



Table 1: System GMM estimations of equation (1)

Dependent Variable: LOG_PCGDP(t)    1       2       3   
LOG_PCGDP(t-1) 0.8614*** 0.8474*** 0.9109***
I(t-1) -0.0148*** -0.012*** -0.0105***
A(t-1) 0.0052** 0.0034** 0.0028
    
ΔA*GDP_LOW 0.0284*
ΔA*GDP_HIGH -0.0196**
ΔI*GDP_LOW 0.0037
ΔI*GDP_HIGH 0.0013
    
Δ A*GINI_LOW 0.0202***
ΔA*GINI_HIGH -0.0201
ΔI*GINI_LOW 0.0006
ΔI*GINI_HIGH 0.0075
    
ΔA*GDP_LOW*GINI_LOW 0.0519***
ΔA*GDP_HIGH*GINI_LOW -0.002
ΔA*GDP_LOW*GINI_HIGH 0.004
ΔA*GDP_HIGH*GINI_HIGH -0.0389**
    
ΔI*GDP_LOW*GINI_LOW 0.0046
ΔI*GDP_HIGH*GINI_LOW -0.0019
ΔI*GDP_LOW*GINI_HIGH 0.0004
ΔI*GDP_HIGH*GINI_HIGH 0.0063
    
ΔI*ΔA*GDP_LOW*GINI_LOW
ΔI*ΔA*GDP_HIGH*GINI_LOW
ΔI*ΔA*GDP_LOW*GINI_HIGH
ΔI*ΔA*GDP_HIGH*GINI_HIGH
    
CONSTANT 1.8217*** 1.7893*** 1.2472***
CONTROLS YES YES YES
    
Obs. 153 153 153
AR1 p-value 0.039 0.082 0.11
J stat p-value 0.199 0.199 0.245

Note: Estimation by System GMM using variables lagged 2 and 3 periods as instruments. Δ represents change between t-2 and t-1. Period dummies in all estimations are not shown. Standard errors clustered by continent. Significance levels: ***1%, **5%, * 10%.

Table 1 presents the main results under System GMM in which urbanisation rates of cities of more than one million inhabitants are used as a proxy for agglomeration at the national level. In sum, the results show a negative effect of inequality and a positive effect of agglomeration on economic growth when both variables are considered by magnitude. With regards to the variables considered in temporal changes, results suggest that the net benefits of agglomeration at the national level not only depend on income levels, as previously highlighted in the literature, but also on its distribution. The positive effects on economic growth from agglomeration are only found when income distribution is relatively equal. By contrast, in rich countries with a highly unequal distribution of income, results suggest a negative effect from agglomeration.6

4.2 Income inequality and long-run economic growth

The second empirical analysis7 focuses on income inequality, and the different mechanisms through which it can affect economic growth. A model of long-run economic growth is estimated using cross-sectional data, and considering initial levels of income inequality, measured with adjusted Gini coefficients, along several controls:

growthi = c+ XiΓ + βIi0 + u1i
(2)

This empirical approach uses a Control Function Approach (CFA) to deconstruct the variance in levels of inequality. Several variables are used to identify the different transmission mechanisms between inequality and growth. For instance, geographical variables associated with the evolution of institutions (e.g. the proportion of land suitable for wheat compared to that suitable for sugar) are used to identify the effects of inequality on growth through institutional development. The model is estimated by Two-Stage-Residual-Inclusion (2SRI). In the first stage, inequality is estimated with regards to the variables associated with each transmission channel under analysis. From this, estimations residuals are obtained. In the second stage, growth is regressed on inequality measures and estimated residuals from the first stage.

The main results are presented in Table 2. OLS results yield a negative but non-significant effect of inequality on economic growth (column 1); while under 2SRI, the coefficient for inequality does become significant. Moreover, results show two significant associations between inequality and growth – one negative and one positive. Variables associated with the domestic market and with institutional development appear as the relevant mechanisms to control for in order to disentangle these two opposing effects. The extended results are presented in my dissertation.8


Table 2: Two opposing effects of inequality
Dependent variable: growth     1         2   
OLS 2SRI
Inequality -0.015 -0.038**
s.e. -0.014 0.019
Resid 0.083**
s.e. 0.04
   
CONSTANT 10.077*** 11.330***
CONTROLS YES YES
Observations 51 51
R2 0.672 0.706
K-P p-value 0.028
Hansen p-value 0.368
Excluded instruments (column 2): death, assassp2, wardrum, Q3, logGDP-1970, pop-growth, mortality, family, wheat-sugar, troppop, mount
Notes: Estimations using bootstrap standard errors (1,000 repetitions). *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01. K-P is the Kleibergen-Paap LM statistic, which tests for the null hypothesis that the matrix of the reduced-form coefficients in the first-stage regression is under-identified. The Hansen J statistic tests the null hypothesis of instrument validity under the assumption of heteroscedasticity.

4.3 Urban concentration, infrastructure, and economic growth

The third and final empirical analysis9 focuses on the relationship between urban concentration and economic growth. The analysis tries to explain regional differences in the urban concentration-growth relationship. In particular, it seeks to explain a previously identified negative effect of concentration on economic growth in Sub Saharan Africa (Brückner 2012). It does so by means of differences in urban environments across countries. For that goal, a model of long-run economic growth (over 5 year periods) is estimated for up to 200 countries using panel data from 1960 to 2010, where the effect of urban concentration is let to vary depending on the level of urban infrastructures:

Δyi = β (logyi,0)+ ψXi,0 + λ1UCi,0 + λ2Gi,0U Ci,0 + πZ1i,0 + ϵi
(3)

Table 3 shows results under System GMM estimations. The results presented are for urban primacy, measured as the percentage of the urban population living in the largest city, as well as access to basic services, measured as the percentage of urban population having access to improved sanitation facilities. While column 1 shows a significant effect of urban concentration, UC, for the world sample, column 2 shows a significant differential and negative effect for Latin America and the Caribbean, and Sub Saharan Africa. However, these differential negative effects seem to be accounted for when an interaction between concentration and urban infrastructure is introduced (columns 3). As it can be seen, the interaction term for Latin America and the Caribbean, as well as that for Sub Saharan Africa become insignificant, while the interaction with urban infrastructure yields highly significant coefficients. As columns 4 and 5 show, infrastructures’ significance is robust to several controls and non-linearities previously identified in the literature, and holds if only developing countries are considered.

Finally, results also hold if we consider only the Sub Saharan Africa sample, and use only external instruments. Exogenous variation given by rainfall data is used for identification, and data on light intensity at night is used as a proxy for income.10 Results under Fixed Effects-Instrumental Variables confirm the role of urban infrastructure in the urban concentration-economic growth relationship. The results are available in my dissertation.11


Table 3: Estimations of equation (3): World and Developing samples
1 2 3 4 5
Sample: World World World Developing Developing
Dependent variable: growth growth growth growth growth
      
UC 0.0054* 0.0049* -0.0396*** 0.1152
(0.0032) (0.0027) (0.0139) (0.0729)
      
UC*LAC -0.0040*** 0.0031
(0.0012) (0.0032)
      
UC*SSA -0.0070** 0.014
(0.003) (0.0122)
      
sanitation 0.0005 -0.008 -0.0137
(0.0132) (0.0089) (0.0112)
      
UC*sanitation 0.0004*** 0.0004** 0.0005**
(0.0001) (0.0002) (0.0002)
      
UC*ln(rgdpch) -0.0360** -0.0354**
(0.0177) (0.0134)
      
UC*(ln(rgdpch))2 0.0021* 0.0018**
(0.0011) (0.0009)
      
UC*region YES
      
Year FE YES YES YES YES YES
Controls YES YES YES YES YES
      
Observations 1204 1204 500 356 356
No. of countries 137 137 131 94 94
AR1 test p-value 0.004 0.002 0.135 0.029 0.043
AR2 test p-value 0.437 0.552 0.353 0.863 0.711
Hansen test p-value 0.047 0.338 0.156 0.325 0.272

5 Concluding remarks and policy implications

This paper briefly presents the main results and contributions form my Ph.D. dissertation and highlights how distributional issues associated with the concentration of resources are not only associated with the process of economic development, but also represent important determinants of long-term economic growth. The spatial and social dimensions of the concentration of resources have been considered: agglomeration and inequality, respectively. In particular, three different contributions to the literature are presented. The first relates to the agglomeration literature and shows that growth-enhancing benefits from agglomeration at the national level are only found in countries with low levels of income inequality. For high-income countries with unequal distribution of income, the evidence points towards growth-deterring congestion costs from increasing agglomeration. The second contribution relates to the inequality-growth literature. The results presented show two-opposing effects of inequality in a single growth model, linking them to the different transmission channels for inequality to affect growth. Finally, the last set of results contributes to the urban concentration-growth literature by providing evidence on the relevance of the urban environment. Urban infrastructure, in particular access to basic services for developing countries, is found to be fundamental to balance benefits and costs that stem from concentration in large cities.

Relevant policy implications arise. In particular, the results obtained allow us to contextualise the discussion on concentration at the national level. The desirability of concentration seems to depend not only on the level of development but also on income distribution, as well as in the physical aspects of the urban environment. Regarding the level of development, in the case of low-income countries there appears to be a conflict between efficiency and equity, at least in the short term, given that increased urban concentration seems desirable for growth but may involve greater inequalities (in line with the World Bank 2009, World Development Report). Indeed, as the analysed data suggests, low-income countries that experienced high rates of economic growth also experienced rapid urbanisation and urban concentration as well as increasing inequalities. For high-income countries, by contrast, a more balanced urban system, in which small and medium-sized cities play a key role, seems more desirable than high urban concentration (in line with Barca et al. 2012). In terms of distribution, for both high- and low-income countries, the fact that the benefits derived from agglomeration depend on income inequality highlights the importance of socio-economic and institutional factors in the debate on urban concentration. Finally, in respects to the urban environment, the analysis confirms recent concerns about urban informal settlements (i.e. slums), which represent poverty traps rather than a transitory state in the process of structural change and economic development. Expansion in access to public services arises as one key policy in this regard.

In sum, the set of results presented highlights rising inequalities, urban congestion, and deficient urban environments as great challenges for sustained and sustainable development that policy makers, especially in developing countries, should take into account and properly address.

References

   Barca F, McCann P, Rodríguez-Pose A (2012) The case for regional development intervention: Place-based versus place-neutral approaches. Journal of Regional Science 52: 134–152

   Brückner M (2012) Economic growth, size of the agricultural sector, and urbanization in Africa. Journal of Urban Economics 71: 26–36

   Brülhart M, Sbergami F (2009) Agglomeration and growth: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Urban Economics 65: 48–63

   Castells-Quintana D (2015) Malthus living in a slum: Urban concentration, infrastructures and economic growth. AQR-IREA working paper 06/2015

   Castells-Quintana D, Royuela V (2014a) Agglomeration, inequality and economic growth. The Annals of Regional Science 52: 343–366

   Castells-Quintana D, Royuela V (2014b) Tracking positive and negative effects of inequality on long-run grown. AQR-IREA working papers 01/2014

   Castells-Quintana D, Royuela V (2015) Are increasing urbanisation and inequalities symptoms of growth? Applied Spatial Analysis and Policy DOI: 10. 1007/s12061-015-9146-2

   Duranton G, Puga D (2004) Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse JF (eds), Handbook of Urban and Regional Economics, Volume Vol. 4: Cities and Geography. North Holland, Amsterdam

   Ehrhart C (2009) The effects of inequality on growth: a survey of the theoretical and empirical literature. ECINEQ working paper series 2009-107

   Galor O (Ed.) (2009) Inequality and Economic Development: The Modern Perspective. Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd, Cheltenham, UK

   Hansen N (1990) Impacts of small and intermediate-sized cities on population distribution: Issues and responses. Regional Development Dialogue 11: 60–76

   Henderson JV (2003) The urbanization process and economic growth: The so-what question. Journal of Economic Growth 8: 47–71

   Henderson JV, Storeygard A, Weil D (2012) Measuring economic growth from outer space. American Economic Review 102: 994–1028

   Kaldor N (1961) Capital accumulation and economic growth. In: Lutz F, Hague D (eds), The Theory of Capital. St. Martins Press, 177–222

   Kuznets S (1955) Economic growth and income inequality. American Economic Review 45: 1–28

   Lewis WA (1954) Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. The Manchester School 22: 139–191

   Marrero G, Rodriguez J (2013) Inequality of opportunity and growth. Journal of Development Economics 104: 107–122

   Milanovic B (2012) Global inequality recalculated and updated: the effect of new PPP estimates on global inequality and 2005 estimates. Journal of Economic Inequality 10: 1–18

   Neves PC, Silva SMT (2013) Inequality and growth: Uncovering the main conclusions from the empirics. Journal of Development Studies 50: 1–21

   Rauch JE (1993) Economic development, urban underemployment, and income inequality. Canadian Journal of Economics 26: 901–18

   Ravallion M (2009) Economic growth and poverty reduction: Do poor countries need to worry about inequality? In: Von Braun J, Hill RE, Pandya-Lorch R (eds), The Poorest and Hungry: Assessments, Analyse, and Actions. IFPRI 2020 Book, Washington DC

   Rosenthal S, Strange W (2004) Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse JF (eds), Handbook of Urban and Regional Economics, Volume Vol. 4: Cities and Geography. North Holland, Amsterdam

   Spence M, Clarke P, Buckley RM (Eds.) (2009) Urbanization and growth. Commission on Growth and Development, World Bank, Washington DC

   Todaro M (1969) A model of labour migration and rural unemployment in less developed countries. American Economic Review 59: 138–148

   Williamson J (1965) Regional inequality and the process on national development. Economic Development and Cultural Change 4: 3–47