Volume 3, Number 2, 2016, 103–124 journal homepage: region.ersa.org
DOI: 10.18335/region.v3i2.130

Pride in the city*

Philip S. Morrison1
1 Victoria University of Wellington, Wellington, New Zealand (email: philip.morrison@vuw.ac.nz) Received: 16 March 2016/Accepted: 17 October 2016

Abstract. Urban pride is an individual and collective response to living in a given city. Unlike other emotions such as life satisfaction or happiness with which it is weakly positively correlated, pride involves stake holding; to be proud of something requires having an investment in its success emotionally, financially or culturally.

For this study I specify a multilevel model based on responses to a five category survey question which asks residents how proud they are in the ‘look and feel of their city’. Responses to the 2008 survey are distributed over almost 6000 residents across 12 cities in New Zealand. Although the primary variation is among individuals, urban pride also varies by city and I show how differences in urban context affect the way different types of stake holding temper urban pride.

JEL classification: R19, R590, I390, H890

Key words: Pride, urban pride, civic pride, city, social identity, multilevel model, New Zealand, Quality of Life Survey

Pride is an emotion that has profound economic consequences and indeed consequences for all areas of human activity (Boulding 1987, pp. 15–16)

1 Introduction

Almost thirty years ago Kenneth E. Boulding proposed a link between power, planning, and pride in a paper entitled, ‘The economics of pride and shame’ (Boulding 1987). Economists, he observed, simply assume that preferences are given but in practice our preferences are strongly determined by our identity which depends very much on the community we live in.

This same relationship was recognised by New Zealand’s Wellington Regional Council when it wrote,

Despite the limitations in being able to monitor our progress regionally, it is known that residents with a strong sense of pride and a sense of community are key to building strong, socially sustainable and connected communities. These people will act as advocates for their region and promote the positive aspects their region has to offer and contribute to improving their neighbourhood (Wellington Regional Council 2011, p. 35)

Notwithstanding the frequent appearance of the term pride in the urban and regional planning discourse very little attention has been paid to the role of urban pride; how it forms in individuals, how it is distributed among residents within and between cities, and above all how it is used in decision making. This lacunae exists in spite of the increasing attention being paid to the way emotion motivates behaviour in general (Davidson et al. 2007), collectively (Sullivan 2014bvon Scheve, Ismer 2013), and within individuals (Lea, Webley 1997)1 1Despite the attention emotions receive in the Davidson et al. (2007) collection, pride as such is not given any attention and this appears to also be the case in papers published so far in the journal Emotion, Space and Society, with the possible exception of Bennett (2013). .

At the same time it is important to differentiate pride from a number of other emotions that are receiving attention, such as life satisfaction and happiness. Pride is unique among the emotions in the way it is tied to stake holding for one only feels pride (or shame) in people, events, or places in which one has a stake, through investment, ownership, or membership.

In this paper I ask three questions. To what extent does urban pride reflects the stake people have in their city? What is the relative role of the city and the individual in the measure of pride? And what characteristics of the city influence the way urban pride responds to stake holding? Each of these questions is addressed by analysing responses to a unique question on urban pride asked in the 2008 New Zealand Quality of Life Survey.

The paper makes four contributions to the urban and regional literature. Firstly, it introduces urban pride as a distinct emotion expressed by most respondents in their city. Secondly, the paper identifies and tests for the several types of urban stake holding. Thirdly, it shows how levels of urban pride vary across residents and cities. And fourthly, it explores the way characteristics of the city can modify the impact of stake holding on urban pride.

1.1 Outline

The paper is in eight sections. Section 2 gathers the scattered literature on pride in support of its defining characteristics and draws a working distinction between civic pride and urban pride. Section 3 introduces the New Zealand Quality of Life Survey. The idea of interacting characteristics of the city with attributes of the individual is integral to the multilevel model introduced in Section 4. The random intercepts model is estimated in Section 5, selected measures of city context are introduced in Section 6, and the multilevel model itself is estimated in Section 7. The paper concludes in Section 8.

2 Pride

Pride is not simply another measure of wellbeing - it is an emotion that results from having a stake in someone, something, or some place. For example: ‘I am proud of my performance’, ‘I am proud we won gold at the Olympics’, or, ‘I am proud of my city’2 . The opposite of pride is shame, which also depends on stake holding, as in ‘I am ashamed of my performance, my country or my city’.

The essential point about pride is that it is based on a prior belief that one has played a role or made a difference in generating the phenomena, event, or condition of interest, even if only in a secondary or peripheral way. Most followers of sports teams feel they contribute simply by being a fan and they are proud of that contribution. Most citizens of countries feel some degree of pride in their country simply because they are born with the right to permanent residence.

Research on pride is scattered over four quite different literatures and each has implications for how we might think about the pride we express in our cities. The psychology literature addresses the way pride regulates individual behaviour (Reissland 1994Rosenblatt 1988). The social identity literature considers the association between pride and group membership and a growing body of work in economics considers the way pride is associated with departures from rational behaviour. Political scientists focus their attention on the pride we exhibit in our country, on national pride.

In psychology, pride has been characterised as an attitude and an expression of personal self-esteem, and is referred to as a ‘social emotion’ (Haidt 2003). The feeling of pride is something that we absorb socially from a young age because pride is closely linked with identity formation (Reissland 1994). Beginning with the development of self-concept as a child, we learn how to associate actions with positive self-esteem and we gain a sense of identity in order to interact socially (Tracy, Robins 20042007).

Tajfel, Turner (1979) show that the groups we belong to are an important source of pride and that much of our self-esteem arises from membership of collectives. Building on this literature, Rosenblatt (1988) shows that individuals who form a group share the same ego ideal and thus identify with one another: “The assertion of a group affiliation appears necessary to make some of the status ‘rub off’.” (Rosenblatt 1988, p. 69). Membership of a collective can also help create a sense of self awareness. As Sullivan points out, “At some level, there is an understanding that the events in question are concerned with ‘us’ and celebrate ‘our’ achievements, values, standards or goals, which implicitly or explicitly constructs or imagines an ‘other’” (Sullivan 2014b, p. 1–2).

Economists have explored the role of pride as an example of behaviour which departs from the ‘rational’. For example, personal pride might inhibit an unemployed person from accepting the dole, or encourage others to work harder for no additional remuneration. Pride is also relevant in understanding conformism in consumer behaviour (Wilcox et al. 2011).

One of the collectives in which pride has long been associated is the nation, the “positive affect that the public feels towards their country” (Smith, Kim 2006, p. 127). National pride involves admiration and stake-holding as well as, “the feeling that one has some kind of share in an achievement or admirable quality” (Evans, Kelley 2002, p. 303). Fabrykant, Magun (2015) go on to make a useful distinction between pride based on objective and normative criteria3 . National pride has been characterised as imagined kinship through shared acceptance of political institutions and norms (Ha, Jang 2015)4 .

The nation and the city are both spatially bound collectives but they differ over the role of choice. Most people do not have a choice of country, whereas it is rare not to have a choice of city therein. Investing in the city is therefore discretionary in a way it is not with the country5 . This may be one of the reasons why, “the ‘sentiment of urban pride’ is becoming more and more popular and widespread as a form of identity that often dominates the national one” (Bell, de Shalit 2011Pachenkov 2014, p. 368). It is also one of the reasons for the growing attention being paid to city branding (Sevin 2014Zenker, Rutter 2014).

2.1 Urban pride

There are three main reasons why scholars have begun to pay attention to urban pride. The first has been to identify ‘soft’ returns as complements to the financial returns to investment. The focus here is on the degree to which local investments enhance pride in the region or country (think most recently of the Olympics in Rio de Janeiro, or London four years earlier)6 . A second reason is to better understand ways of fostering urban pride (Trueman et al. 2004), notably through city promotion (Anttiroiko 2015). Both these literatures focus primarily on the aggregate or collective consequences of urban pride rather than the way pride is distributed across city residents themselves.

A third reason has been to understand how pride has been invoked in support of urban redevelopment. Williams (1995), for example, has shown how the term urban pride has been used in the United Kingdom to promote a realignment of urban regeneration policy based on public-private sector partnerships7 . He argues that so-called City Pride experiments of the early 1990s were only superficially about city pride and were more about procurement and delivery of resources for the development of property8 . As such, city pride has been used as a smokescreen for a much narrower set of interests, public and private (Randall 1995)9 .

In a more recent paper, Collins (2016) considers the way in which cities promote and defend local identity and autonomy through the evocation of ‘civic pride’. The contrast between Collin’s perspective and the one I take below invites a distinction between civic pride as the term is used by various urban leaders and spokespersons, and what I introduce here as urban pride, the pride expressed by individual residents in their city. According to this distinction, civic pride refers to pride packaged from the ‘top’ by city leaders and urban pride to pride expressed from ‘below’, by individual residents.

Defined in this way civic pride and urban pride represent different perspectives and are likely to be measured and analysed in different ways. For example, Collins applies a discourse analysis to recent urban documents and local media as a way of examining how civic pride is mobilised and promoted within and beyond the city. By contrast, my paper is concerned with how and why urban pride is expressed by individuals and the relative effect of the city on those relationships. I apply a statistical model in order to understand the implied multilevel variance.

One of the possibilities that emerges from the identification of these two types of pride, civic and urban, is that the view from the ‘top’, may not be highly correlated with the view from the ‘below’. One of the reasons for this disjuncture is statistical: civic pride is a packaged average based largely on anecdote whereas urban pride is a distribution based on a representative sample of city residents. The latter can range from very high levels of urban pride expressed by residents who are passionate about their city through to quite negative views expressed by those who are actively hostile. As I show below, the actual variance is quite wide, complex, and in need of understanding.

2.2 Hypotheses

The broad hypothesis of this paper is that the level of urban pride returned by city residents is a function of their individual and collective stake in the city. Without stake holding there is no urban pride and I propose four types: emotional, financial, cultural, and civic stakeholding. Although these respective stakes can operate independently they can also be reinforcing such as when the emotional and cultural combine, or the financial and civic join forces.

The first form of stake holding is the ‘emotional’, the way people feel about the city and what it means to them personally. This form of sentimental attachment takes time to develop and deepen and for this reason it is positively associated with the duration of residence. Those residents whose families have grown up in the city and whose friends continue to live there have a major stake in their continuing presence in the city. The 2011 earthquake in Christchurch, New Zealand was a salient reminder of the emotional cost to residents who experienced their city being removed from under them.

The second form of stake holding is ‘financial’. Prime candidates are home owners and those in full-time employment who have the means to invest locally. Their livelihood is tied materially to the fortunes of the city. By extension, those who find it difficult to get an economic foothold in the city are likely to have a lower stake which is expected to be reflected in lower levels of urban pride.

The third type of stake holding I term ‘cultural’ and involves those whose sense of collective (as opposed to personal) identity is linked to the way the city meets their cultural needs. Their initial support is tied to the sharing of their location with others like them and their pride in their city largely reflects what living in the city means to them in identity terms.

The fourth type of stake holding I refer to as ‘civic’ for it refers to the level of engagement people have with the leadership, administration, and general running of the city.

There have been very few attempts to actually measure and quantify urban pride. Some initial steps were made in response to a perceived reduction in community belonging associated with the restructuring of cities and towns in the United Kingdom (e.g. Wood 2006)10 . The restructuring of the New Zealand economy in the 1980s and 1990s prompted a similar response when local governments realised that evidence on quality of local life and wellbeing was needed if they were to make credible cases for devolution. The result was the introduction of an on-going survey aimed at capturing the quality of urban life in the late 1990s, the New Zealand Quality of Life Survey11 .

3 The Quality of Life Survey

The Quality of Life Survey is a multi-agency research project designed to explore quality of life issues every two years in a selection of New Zealand cities12 . The 2008 survey was a partnership between twelve New Zealand City Councils and the Ministry of Social Development. The survey captures New Zealand residents’ perceptions of their quality of life, health and wellbeing, crime and safety, community, culture and social networks, city council decision making processes, environment, public transport, lifestyle, and work and study13 .

The 2008 survey was not the latest available at the time of writing. It was selected for this particular study because a subsequent amalgamation of the four previously separate Auckland cities to form a new unitary authority reduced the number of urban areas from 12 to 8 thus reducing the range of cities which could be included14 . The locations of the twelve cities covered in the 2008 survey are shown in Figure 1.


PIC

1. Rodney 2. North Shore 3. Waitakere 4. Auckland 5. Manukau 6. Hamilton
7. Tauranga 8. Porirua 9. Hutt 10. Wellington 11. Christchurch 12. Dunedin

Note: Although Rodney is a district rather than a city, I retain the survey’s own description of it as a city.

Source: Quality of Life Team (2009)

Figure 1: The location of the twelve cities included in the Quality of Life project. New Zealand, 2008


The twelve cities include almost 59 percent of the country’s total population. The largest city, as of the 2006 census, was Auckland City (404.6 thousand), followed by Christchurch (348.4), Manukau (329), and North Shore (205.6). The smallest was Porirua City (48.5). As Figure 1 shows, eight of the twelve cities were located in either the Auckland or Wellington Metropolitan areas.

Each city is divided into electoral wards which are a contiguous areal groupings of relatively similar neighbourhoods. The four large cities in Auckland are divided into three to six wards each, Wellington City into five wards and Christchurch into seven. The total number of wards over the 12 cities is 5915 . The average number of sampled individuals per ward is 103 although they range in size from a minimum sample of 2 to a maximum of 230 people. Some individuals were not able to be assigned to wards thus reducing the usable sample size when wards are analysed from 6117 to 609316 .

3.1 Measuring urban pride

The measure of urban pride used in this paper are the responses to the following question: “On a scale of one to five where one is strongly disagree and five is strongly agree, rate your agreement with the statement, ‘I feel a sense of pride in the way [my city] looks and feels’.”17

The general tendency was for New Zealand city dwellers to return at least some level of pride in their city. The responses tabulated in Table 1 show that almost 63 percent (45.2 + 19.9) felt positively about ‘how their city looked and felt’. Over one quarter were ambivalent in that they neither agreed nor disagreed, and fewer than 10 percent (7.7) did not feel a sense of urban pride as defined.


Table 1: Responses to the statement “I feel a sense of pride in the way [my city] looks and feels”. Twelve New Zealand cities, 2008
Response Frequency Percent Cumulative Percent
Strongly disagree 98 1.5 1.5
Disagree 443 6.6 8.0
Neutral 1,786 26.5 34.6
Agree 3,068 45.6 80.1
Strongly agree 1,341 19.9 100
Total 6,736 100.0
Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

Note: Excludes 21 respondents who did not know.


The urban pride question generates responses on an ordinal scale. While methods of analysing such responses are well developed (Hosmer, Lemeshow 2000McKelvey, Zovoina 1975) it is now common for quantitative analysis of related wellbeing questions to assume a cardinal level of measurement (Ferrer-i Carbonell, Frijters 2004). The estimated coefficients are much easier to interpret and accord very closely with the relative magnitudes estimated by the ordinal logit model (Kristoffersen 2010)18 .

Treating urban pride as a continuous measure yields a mean 3.71 on the 1-5 scale (SD=0.87). The highest average level of pride, 4.12, was reported by residents of Wellington City (the country’s capital), and the lowest were returned by residents in the City of Manukau, 3.33, located within the wider Auckland region. The intermediate levels of urban pride in descending order were the cities of North Shore 3.90, Dunedin 3.87, Tauranga, and Hamilton, 3.83 Christchurch 3.82, Waitakere, 3.62 Lower Hutt, 3.61 Porirua, 3.57 Rodney, 3.56 and Auckland, 3.48.

In summary, the New Zealand Quality of Life survey has provided the research community with an opportunity to explore the distribution of urban pride across the country’s cities. Urban pride is captured in a single measure which asks respondents to declare how strongly they agree they feel a sense of pride in the way their city looks and feels. Following common practice in studies of subjective wellbeing, I treat the ordinal responses as cardinal and will now model this variation as a function of individual stake holding and city characteristics19 .

4 The two level model

Most studies of emotional response apply the conventional OLS ‘total’ regression model to the relationship between the outcome y and arguments X in order to estimate the fixed parameters α and β, where i refers to the individual20 .

yyyi = α0 + βXi + ϵϵϵi
(1)

In such a model the random or allowed-to-vary element is captured by ϵϵϵ, the mean or expected value of which is assumed to be zero. An accompanying assumption is that there is constant variability in ϵϵϵi and no autocorrelation. The assumption is necessary if the variance of the error term is to be characterised by a single parameter σϵ2.21

The application of equation (1) would fail to address two integral features of urban pride: that pride is likely to be contagious within the city, as well as being responsive to differences between cities. The presence of contagion and inter-city differences violates the i.i.d assumptions of the OLS regression model implicit in ϵϵϵ and renders the occurrence of type 1 errors more likely (Kreft, du Leeuw 2006Rabe-Hesketh, Skrondal 2008).

A more suitable model would allow average levels of urban pride to vary across cities so that the average level of urban pride in the jth city is the sum of the city-wide average, α0, plus a varying difference uuuj.22 . The fixed intercept, α0, would represent the average level of urban pride across all the cities and the variance, σμ2, would measure the inter-city variability about the average23 .

a0j = α0 + uuuj
(2)

Combining the micro equation of (1) and the macro equation of (2) produces the two-level mixed model of equation (3).24

yyyij = α0 + βxij + (uuuj + ϵϵϵij)
(3)

An initial step in applying this random intercepts model is to estimate the proportion of the variance attributable to differences among individuals at one level and cities at the other. In this null model,

yyyij = α0 + (uuuj + ϵϵϵij)
(4)

where the proportion of the variance attributable to individuals is

--σ2ϵ---
σ2ϵ +σ2μ

and the variation across cities is

--σ2μ---
σ2ϵ +σ2μ

which is referred to as the intra-class correlation (ICC).


Table 2: Intra-class correlation coefficients: cities, wards, cities and wards. New Zealand 2008
Levels ICC SE
95% confidence interval
Cities 0.06 0.02   0.03 0.12
Wards 0.07 0.01   0.05 0.11
Cities/Wards 0.06 0.02   0.02 0.12
Wards/Cities 0.07 0.02   0.03 0.13
Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.


PIC

Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

Figure 2: Inter-city variation in urban pride: predicted random intercepts by city. New Zealand 2008.


In this application, the intra-class correlation is a measure of the degree to which individuals share the experiences of living in the same city. If the correlation is greater than zero then there is a case for applying a random coefficients model and its extension as a multilevel model. The presumption in such a step is that the differences we see in the level of urban pride from one city to another is not due simply to differences in the levels of stake holding by individual residents (the composition effect) but arise in part from differences among the cities themselves (the context effect).

An intra-class correlation coefficient of 5.7 percent implies that differences in levels of urban pride across the 12 cities account for nearly 6 percent of the variance in urban pride (Table 2). The rest, 94 percent, is due to the differences among individuals. A similar partitioning of the variance applies if clustering is confined to the 59 wards, however since wards are nested within cities, both variances are reduced slightly when they are both included; to 5.5 and 6.6 percent, respectively25 .

In summary, since urban pride varies both within and between cities as a possible result of both contagion and intercity differences, the standard OLS regression model is better replaced by one which treats the city as a random variable.

5 A random intercepts model

The random intercept model of equation (4) implies a different intercept term for each city, α + μj; j = 1,,12. These terms are not estimated directly but we can use linear unbiased predictions (BLUPS) of their random effects as shown in Figure 2. At one extreme, the City of Manukau has a prediction one half a standard deviation lower than the grand mean, and Wellington City almost half a standard deviation higher. These differences in the average level of urban pride across the twelve New Zealand cities are immediately recognised by New Zealand audiences (often with a smile).

Recognising that average levels of urban pride vary across New Zealand cities does not in itself address the fact that urban pride may vary within cities. We can identify variation both within and between cities by adding the neighbourhood intercept term uuu* to equation (3), that is, uuuj + uuu* + ϵϵϵij. Ward random effects are not calculated directly either but we can overlay their best linear unbiased predictions as in Figure 3. The median in each box reflects the city random intercepts while the length of the boxes (and the outliers) indicates the degree of inter-ward variation within each city.


PIC

Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

Figure 3: Ward to ward variation in urban pride within cities: predicted random intercepts by wards within cities. New Zealand 2008.


As Figure 3 shows, the inter-ward variation in urban pride varies noticeably from one city to another, being relatively wide in Rodney and Manukau and Porirua and comparatively narrow in Wellington and Auckland.

5.1 Differences among residents

As expected, urban pride varies across cities. It also appears that levels of urban pride vary by ward. We now turn to the third possible source of variation – differences among individuals themselves.

Nine separate sources of individual stake holding along with two controls are listed under the four headings in Table 3 together with their respective means and standard deviation. Each is a binary variable coded so that the expected sign is positively correlated with urban pride. The emotional stake in the city is represented by two variables. The first is duration of residence and we learn that over 70 percent of residents had lived in their city for a decade or more. Notwithstanding this long average association with the city, only 55.3 percent felt their neighbourhood offered them a sense of community.


Table 3: Measures of stake holding and controls used in the modelling of urban pride. New Zealand, 2008
Variable Description Mean Std Dev
Controls
Female Female 0.53 0.50
Health Health good or very good 0.61 0.49
    
Emotional stakes
Duration Resident in city 10 years + 0.70 0.46
Community Sense of community 0.55 0.50
    
Financial stakes
Owner Home owner 0.62 0.49
Not employed Not employed 0.26 0.44
Enough Income meets everyday needs 0.87 0.34
    
Cultural stake
Minority Non-European 0.23 0.42
    
Civic stakes
Safe Feel safe in central city 0.63 0.48
Clean No rubbish noticed 0.49 0.50
Council Councidence in Council decisions 0.46 0.50
Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

Note: The relevant survey questions are listed in the Appendix.


Three measures are designed to capture residents’ financial stake in the city: homeownership (62 percent)26 , employment (over three quarters) and nearly 87 percent said they had enough money to live on27 . Having a cultural stake in the city is represented by a single variable, membership of a minority ethnic group, collected here under the term non-European (23 percent)28 . Three measures were used to identify civic stake holding: whether the respondent felt safe or very safe in their city centre during the day (63.4%), whether they identified litter and rubbish lying on the street (49.3%), and whether they agreed that ‘the council makes decisions that are in the best interests of their city’ (45.5 %)29 . The two controls in Table 3 reveal a slight majority of women in the sample (52.8%), and a population where nearly 61 percent of respondents are in Good or Very Good Health.

5.2 The correlation matrix

The pairwise correlation matrix of the 11 variables listed above is reproduced in Table 4. Although the variance inflation factor was low at 1.05 and tolerances were all over 0.9, almost half the pairwise correlations were statistically significant (p 0.05 in bold italics)30 .


Table 4: Correlation matrix of urban pride arguments. New Zealand, 2008
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
1 Female 1.00
2 Health 0.04 1.00
3 Duration 0.04 -0.01 1.00
4 Community 0.04 0.04 0.03 1.00
5 Owner 0.04 0.01 0.06 0.09 1.00
6 Not employed 0.12 -0.10 0.05 0.08 -0.02 1.00
7 Enough 0.01 0.10 0.04 0.01 0.10 -0.07 1.00
8 Minority -0.04 -0.11 -0.14 0.06 -0.18 -0.06 -0.10 1.00
9 Safe -0.06 0.12 0.00 0.01 -0.05 0.02 0.04 -0.08 1.00
10 Clean -0.03 0.02 -0.05 0.04 0.02 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.11 1.00
11 Council 0.00 0.03 -0.05 0.09 -0.13 0.03 0.02 0.10 0.07 0.09
Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

Number of observations: Min 5957 to Max 6093.


The connections implied by this correlation matrix are instructive. Reading the statistically significant correlations by column shows that women (column 1) were more likely to feel a sense of community in their neighbourhood, were less likely to be employed, and felt less safe within the city centre during the day. From column 2 we learn that good health was associated with being employed, having enough money, being defined as European, and feeling safe. Column 3, duration, identifies those who lived in the city for a decade. They are more likely to be home owners, less likely to be employed or identify as a minority. They are also more likely to be critical of the city in terms of its cleanliness and the extent to which the council represents the interests of the majority.

Feeling a sense of community (column 4) is positively correlated with home ownership, not being employed, being a minority, seeing the city as clean, and feeling positive about council. Home ownership (column 5), is associated with having enough money and not being a minority, but also not feeling safe in the city centre or agreeing that council works in the best interests of the majority. Not being employed (column 6) is negatively associated with having enough money and not identifying with minority status. Having enough money (column 7) is a characteristic of minorities, as is feeling very safe in the city centre, but feeling less positive about council decisions. Identification with a minority is negatively correlated with feeling safe in the central city but positively associated with approval of council. Those who feel safe in the city also view the city as clean and have a positive view of council (column 9). Appreciating a clean city and viewing council positively are positively correlated (column 10).

The results of applying the random intercepts model (equation 3) are presented in Table 5. The results only include city random effects because the inter-ward intra-class correlation dropped to almost zero. In other words, ward to ward differences in urban pride were due almost entirely to population composition effects rather than to unique contexts characteristic of the wards themselves31 . Cities, rather than wards within them, are the primary object of city pride as the city pride question itself implies.


Table 5: The distribution of urban pride. Stake holding fixed effects and city random effects. New Zealand, 2008
Variable
Description
Coef.
Std Err.
z P > |z|
FIXED EFFECTS
         
Controls
Female Female 0.10   0.02 4.91 0.00
Health Health good or very good 0.06 0.21 3.01 0.00
         
Emotional stakes
Duration
Resident in city for 10 years or more
0.11 0.02 4.78 0.00
Community Sense of community 0.24 0.02 11.22 0.00
         
Financial stakes
Owner Home owner 0.08 0.08 3.80 0.00
Not employed Not employed 0.06 0.02 2.45 0.01
Enough Income meets everyday needs 0.10 0.03 3.17 0.00
         
Cultural stakes
Minority Non-European 0.20 0.03 7.44 0.00
         
Civic stakes
Safe Feel safe in the central city 0.21 0.02 9.37 0.00
Clean No rubbish noticed 0.23 0.02 11.20 0.00
Council Confidence in council decisions 0.37 0.02 17.68 0.00
         
Constant 2.80 0.07 37.36 0.00
         
RANDOM EFFECTS
         
Cities Constant 0.04 0.02
Residual 0.61 0.01
         
Number of cases
5867
Log likelihood
-6897
.
12
LR vs linear model test
348
.
72
Wald chi, pr=0
982
.
88
Degrees of freedom
14
AIC
13822
.
23
Intraclass correlation
0
.
07
Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

Note: Estimates from the MIXED model, Stata14.


The first point to note from the fixed effects estimates in Table 5 is that urban pride is most strongly associated with civic stake holding, and with the confidence people have that their council works in their best interests. Those supporting Council have a mean level of urban pride which is over one third (0.37%) of a unit higher than the rest of the population on the 1-5 urban pride scale. Those who feel a sense of community, see a clean city, and feel safe in its centre have a mean pride between a fifth and a quarter of a unit higher than the base population. Being non-European has a similar effect (0.20).

Having lived in the city for a decade or more has a weaker but still positive effect on urban pride, as does being female and being in good health. Having enough money to meet every day needs and being a homeowner are less important but still positive, increasing urban pride by at 0.10 and 0.08 of a unit, respectively. Being in retirement (most of those not employed) also contributes (0.06).

The model with covariates is a clear improvement over the null model with cities alone. In the absence of a clear equivalent of the r-squared statistic, R2, I use the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) (-2log (likelihood) + 2k), where k is the number of model parameters and -2log (likelihood) is the deviance statistic. The difference between the null model and the model reported in Table 5 in AIC terms is 1901 = 15723-13822.

In summary, when it comes to accounting for the way urban pride varies over the population, the measures introduced to represent stake holding clearly matter. Urban pride is most sensitive to the degree to which council is recognised as listening to the people, a result which highlights the role of city leadership (Boezeman, Ellemers 2014). Feeling a sense of community, appreciating a clean city, and feeling safe in the city centre all contribute to a sense of urban pride as does being a member of an ethnic minority. Having a financial stake in the city (having enough income and being a homeowner) also matters but not to the degree anticipated.

6 City context

The results I have summarised from Table 5 suggest that urban pride reflects a sense of collective achievement rather than personal success. We might ask in addition whether cities themselves raise or lower urban pride. In the absence of an empirical literature on urban pride, I start with four relatively generic attributes of the city: its population size, its level of affluence, the share of Europeans in the population, and the confidence people have in its civic leadership. It is possible to think of a range of other measures such as the quality of the environment, but these will remain as suggested refinements only.

The distributions of the city’s four characteristics are shown in Table 6 along with the average level of pride in each city. The population figure is drawn from the nearest population census (2006) as are the proportion of individuals with pre-tax incomes of over $70,000 per annum, and the proportion of Europeans in the city. The fourth variable, civic engagement, is aggregated from the sample responses.


Table 6: Selected characteristics of the twelve New Zealand cities.
City Pride
Population(’000)
Affluence European Council
Rodney District 3.56    89.56 0.10 0.95 0.30
North Shore City 3.90 205.61 0.13 0.77 0.44
Waitakere City 3.62 186.44 0.07 0.67 0.48
Auckland City 3.48 404.66 0.14 0.62 0.40
Manukau City 3.33 323.97 0.07 0.46 0.51
Hamilton City 3.83 129.25 0.07 0.76 0.57
Tauranga City 3.87 103.64 0.06 0.88 0.40
Porirua City 3.57 48.55 0.10 0.66 0.51
Lower Hutt City 3.61 86.93 0.09 0.75 0.47
Wellington City 4.12 179.47 0.17 0.81 0.50
Christchurch City 3.82 348.44 0.07 0.88 0.41
Dunedin City 3.88 118.68 0.05 0.92 0.46
Source: Census of Population and Dwellings, 2006 and Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

The fixed effects coefficients at the individual level remained remarkably stable when each of these city level measures is added to the model singly or together. The exception is the variable ‘minority’ whose influence on urban pride drops as a result of the high concentration of the minority population in the two cities of Manukau and Porirua.

While the difference between the cities themselves may not account for much of the variance in urban pride, the contexts they represent may still condition the marginal effect of individual attributes. This tempering turns out to be the principle role of the city when it comes to understanding urban pride.

7 The multilevel model

Urban pride is a two-way street because it reflects attributes of both the residents and the characteristics of the city. However, while New Zealand cities do differ in size and composition, their differences appear to have little influence in raising or lowering urban pride. Rather, the role of the characteristics of the city is to modify the way particular forms of stake holding raise or lower urban pride.

I illustrate this last point by showing that the negative effect on urban pride of not having enough money has greater effect in more affluent cities, that the level of urban pride exhibited by minorities rises as their share of the population increases, and that duration of residence modifies the way city-wide support of the local city council affects urban pride. These do not exhaust the possible interactions between individuals and their city of course, but they do indicate the way the city can influence the level of urban pride people express.

7.1 The influence of context on financial stake holding

The motivation for the first of these illustrations is the possible role of relativities. The argument here is that it is not just financial wellbeing that moderates one’s pride in the city but one’s relative position. Recall from Table 6, that affluence at the city level is measured as the proportion of the 2006 census population who earn more than $70,000 per annum (before tax). The range across New Zealand cities is quite wide, from a low of five percent in Dunedin City through to 17 percent in the capital, Wellington City. The testable proposition is that not having enough money ‘to meet every day needs’ may have a greater negative effect on urban pride in more affluent cities because it is associated with lower relative rank, over and above the pride reducing effects of material deprivation itself. The secondary argument is that this relationship will vary with homeownership.

I have already shown that, as a characteristic of the city, affluence (a level 2 variable) plays a very limited role in raising or lowering urban pride. However, when having enough money (a level 1 variable) is interacted with city affluence separately for owners and renters, renters without enough money (typically younger residents) return higher levels of urban pride in cities which are more affluent. This result is apparent in the solid line in the right panel of Figure 4. By contrast, homeowners without enough money (typically older residents) return lower levels of urban pride in more affluent cities (solid line, left panel of Figure 4).


PIC

Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008 and Census of Population and Dwellings, 2006.

Note: With the same fixed and random effects as in Table 5 adding the interaction of enough x owner x affluence term yields a coefficient of -3.72 and a standard error of 1.91 and a z of -1.95 and p > (z) of 0.052. The 95% confidence intervals are plotted.

Figure 4: The effect of ‘not having enough money’ on urban pride in more affluent cities by housing tenure. New Zealand, 2008


By contrast, renters and owners who say they have enough money to meet daily needs both return higher levels of urban pride in more affluent cities (the dashed lines in Figure 4) with city affluence having a more marked influence on homeowners’ urban pride. The results presented in both panels of Figure 4 are plausible in light of the role I have attributed to stake holding.

7.2 Context influences on cultural stake holding

My second illustration addresses the impact minority ethnic status has on urban pride. My expectation was that minorities would return higher levels of pride in cities the larger their share of the population because the relative size of the minority groups have been shown to contribute to both a greater sense of identity and collective strength (Tyler, Blader 2001, p. 209–210). My expectation in the case of non-Europeans living in New Zealand cities therefore was that their sense of identity would diminish as their share of the population fell and this would be reflected in the level of pride they expressed in their city. The evidence in this case rests on the interaction of the level 2 variable ‘European’ and the level 1 variable ‘minority’.


PIC

Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008 and Census of Population and Dwellings, 2006.

Note: With the fixed effects of Table 5 in the model, the addition of the cross-level term (minority x European) is β = -0.710 ( SE=0.19; z= -3.74).

Figure 5: The positive impact of minority status on urban pride falls as the proportion of Europeans in the city rises. New Zealand, 2008


Figure 5 offers support for the minority ‘share’ hypothesis. The fixed effects results of Table 5 have minorities returning higher levels of urban pride than the European majority. Introducing a city x minority cross-level effect reveals how much urban pride rises as the proportion of Europeans in the city increases. This rise is much slower in the case of minorities (dashed line) and the urban pride converges when the proportion of Europeans in the city approaches its maximum. In other words, while members of ethnic minorities in New Zealand return higher levels of urban pride than the much larger number of Europeans, any such difference falls as the proportion of Europeans rises, reflecting an expected diminution in the social and cultural identity of non-Europeans.

7.3 Does the urban pride effect of support for Councils vary with duration of residence?

A third possible factor influencing urban pride is duration of residence. However, discerning this interaction is more complicated because the relationship could conceivably be two-way. The length of residence in a city could be a function of as well as an influence on pride: being proud of the city may encourage staying, and those who are not particularly proud of their city may be more likely to leave. The endogeneity present in this relationship renders my investigation of this relationship quite exploratory.

Those who see City Councils acting in the interests of the majority return higher levels of urban pride (as I showed in Table 5). However it is possible that this relationship is affected by how long people have lived in the city. The available duration of residence variable only separates those who are relatively new to the city, from those who have lived there for more than a decade. (Finer partitions beyond the decade offered little further insight).

Figure 6, which interacts duration of residence with the proportion of the city supporting Council, suggests that the positive relationship between urban pride and the city’s confidence in its council only applies to the longer term residents. The pride experienced by relative new comers in their city appears unaffected by the confidence the city has in its council. The 95% confidence intervals are relatively wide in this case but with the fixed effects of Table 5 in the model the interaction between the level 1 variable duration and the level 2 variable Council is statistically significant.


PIC

Source: Quality of Life Survey, 2008.

Note: The estimate of the Council x duration interaction term is β = 0.631 (se= 0.32), z = 1.97.

Figure 6: The estimated relationship between urban pride and city wide support for Council: longer vs. shorter term residents. New Zealand, 2008


To summarise Section 7, when it comes to statistically accounting for the variance in the pride we express in our cities, city characteristics themselves account for relatively little. Most of the variance in urban pride comes down to the stake individuals have in their city. Having said that, exactly how people’s stake in the city affects their level of urban pride is influenced by the characteristics of the city. Being able to demonstrate this contingency and the way in which city context modifies the effect of stake holding on urban pride is one of the primary findings of this paper, and the main reason for reporting the multilevel model.

8 Conclusions

Collins’ recent study of pride in British cities suggested that, “civic pride has been under-theorised in geography and that the emotional meanings of pride need to be better understood” (Collins 2016, p. 185). I agree, and in response, I have drawn a distinction between civic pride as promulgated by city leaders and the emotion expressed by individual residents themselves which I have termed ‘urban pride’. Such a contrast is designed to expose the difference between city spokespersons claiming citizens are proud of their city and individuals who are free to express their own personal level of urban pride. The later has the value of demonstrating the way different levels of urban pride are distributed both within and between cities.

Civic pride in the sense above is a dimension of self-esteem which city politicians and planners go to great lengths to foster among their citizens. In practice however, most cities are content simply to anecdote civic pride when it suits, and few make a serious attempt to actually measure the level of urban pride empirically. New Zealand cities may have been an exception in this respect by ensuring that their Quality of Life Survey actually included a question on the pride their residents have in their city.

In this paper I have sketched in a theory of urban pride based on stake holding as it applies to the city. I identified four primary sources: the stake holding that accrues through emotional attachment to the city, financial investment in the city, cultural affiliation and civic engagement. I then specified a multilevel model in order to empirically test the relative influence of such stake holding on urban pride. By drawing on a large random sample from twelve cities in an otherwise relatively homogeneous country like New Zealand, I have been able to assess the degree to which the stake individuals have in the city influences how proud they feel.

As a result of the Urban Consortium funding a large sample of nearly 6000 residents in 2008, I have been able to show that certain types of stake holding have more influence than others. After controlling for gender and self-assessed health, individuals positively disposed towards their council, who felt safe and saw their city as clean and well maintained were more likely to declare such pride. This is also true of those who felt a sense of community. I also learned that, other things equal, those who owned their dwelling and who felt they earned enough to meet every day needs also enjoyed higher levels of urban pride. When it came to emotional stake holding, I was able to show that ethnic minorities return higher levels of urban pride as their share of the city population increased.

I went into this project expecting that the identified characteristics of cities themselves would have a major influence on the level of urban pride citizens report. This was not the case. Most of the measurable variance turned out to be due to individual stake holding. By explicitly testing for city x individual interaction (cross level effects) estimates from the multilevel model revealed that city characteristics conditioned the way individual stakes in the city influenced urban pride. They revealed how the negative effect on urban pride of not having enough money is more marked in more affluent cities, how the higher levels of urban pride exhibited by minorities increased as their share of the population in the city rose, and how duration of residence affects the way aggregate support of city councils conditioned citizens level of urban pride.

Although broader than Kenneth Boulding’s proposition on stake holding, the above findings are consistent with his argument on pride and shame (Boulding 1987). At the same time my analysis has rested on a single definition of urban pride – pride in the ‘look and feel of your city’. There are many other ways of asking about urban pride and if and when they are applied we may discover other ways in which stake holding alters the pride we hold in our cities.

Measures of urban pride have been argued to be among the ‘soft’ returns that accrue to accumulated investment in the city. If city leaders are tempted to use such ‘soft’ measures alongside the standard financial measures, then we need to know a great deal more about what people mean by urban pride, what generates the emotion, how it takes root and among whom, in what circumstances, and in what kinds of cities. As we have learned from the burgeoning literature on subjective wellbeing, investments in the community are unlikely to carry the force of change unless their returns can be measured (Stiglitz et al. 2009). So far, urban pride has remained a largely unmeasured response to our feelings toward our city and as such remains an unexploited barometer of the distributional consequences of public and private investment.

References

   Anttiroiko AV (2015) City branding as a response to global intercity competition. Growth and change 46: 233–252. CrossRef.

   Bell DA, de Shalit A (2011) The spirit of cities. Why identity of a city matters in a global age. Princeton University Press, Oxford

   Bennett K (2013) Emotion and place promotion: passionate about a former coalfield. Emotion, space and society 8: 1–10. CrossRef.

   Boezeman EJ, Ellemers N (2014) Volunteer leadership: the role of pride and respect in organisational identification and leadership satisfaction. Leadership 10: 160–173. CrossRef.

   Boulding KE (1987) The economics of pride and shame. Atlantic Economic Journal 15: 10–19. CrossRef.

   Collins T (2016) Urban civic pride and the new localism. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 41: 175–186. CrossRef.

   Cummins RA (2009) The Australian Unity Wellbeing Index 2001-2008: variations in subjective wellbeing linked with major events and inflation. Social Indicators Network News 96: 1–4

   Davidson J, Smith M, Bondi L (2007) Emotional geographies. Ashgate, Hamshire, UK. CrossRef.

   Evans MDR, Kelley J (2002) National pride in the developed world: survey data from 24 nations. International journal of public opinion research 14: 304–336. CrossRef.

   Fabrykant M, Magun V (2015) Grounded and normative dimensions of national pride in comparative perspective. Higher School of Economics Research Paper, National Research University Higher School of Economics, Moscow

   Ferrer-i Carbonell A, Frijters P (2004) How important is methodology for the estimates of the determinants of happiness? The Economic Journal 114: 641–659. CrossRef.

   Ha SE, Jang SJ (2015) National identity, national pride, and happiness: The case of South Korea. Social Indicators research 121: 471–482. CrossRef.

   Haidt J (2003) The moral emotions. In: Davidson RJ, Scherer KR, Goldsmith HH (eds), Handbook of affective sciences. Oxford University Press, Oxford, England, 852–870

   Helliwell JF, Putnam RD (2004) The social context of well-being. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 359: 1435–46. CrossRef.

   Hosmer DW, Lemeshow S (2000) Applied logistic regression. John Wiley, Sons Ltd, New York. CrossRef.

   Hox J (2002) Multilevel analysis. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJ. CrossRef.

   Jones K (1991) Specifying and estimating multi-level models for geographical research. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 16: 148–159. CrossRef.

   Jones K, Johnston J, Pattie CJ (1992) People, places and regions: exploring the uses of multi-level modelling in the analysis of electoral data. British Journal of Political Science 22: 343–380. CrossRef.

   Kelly J (1998) Attachment to one’s city. Australian Social Monitor 1: 14–15

   Kreft I, du Leeuw J (2006) Introducing multilevel modelling. London. CrossRef.

   Kristoffersen I (2010) The metrics of subjective wellbeing: cardinal neutrality and additivity. The Economic Record 86: 98–123. CrossRef.

   Lea SEG, Webley P (1997) Pride in economic psychology. Journal of Economic Psychology 18: 323–340. CrossRef.

   Luke DA (2004) Multilevel modelling. Sage Publications, London. CrossRef.

   McKelvey RD, Zovoina W (1975) A statistical model for the analysis of ordinal level dependent variables. Journal of Mathematical Sociology 4: 103–120. CrossRef.

   Morrison PS (2007) Subjective well-being and the city. Social Policy Journal of New Zealand 30: 74–103

   Morrison PS (2011) Local expressions of subjective well-being: the New Zealand experience. Regional Studies 45: 1039–1058. CrossRef.

   Pachenkov O (2014) Review of: Da bell, a de-shalit (2011) why identity of a city matters in a global age. oxford: Princeton university press. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 38: 366–368. CrossRef.

   Pawlowski T, Downward P, Rasciute S (2014) Does national pride from international sporting success contribute to well-being? an international investigation. Sport Management Review 17: 121–132. CrossRef.

   Quality of Life Team (2009) Quality of life survey 2008. National report, Nielsen, Wellington

   Rabe-Hesketh S, Skrondal A (2008) Multilevel and longitudinal modeling using Stata. Stata Press, College Station, Texas. CrossRef.

   Randall S (1995) City pride - from ‘municipal socialism’ to ‘municipal capitalism’? Critical Social Policy 15: 40–59. CrossRef.

   Reeskens T, Wright M (2011) Subjective well-being and national satisfaction: taking seriously the “proud of what?” question. Psychological Science 22: 1460–1462. CrossRef.

   Reissland N (1994) The socialisation of pride in young children. International journal of behavioural development 17: 541–552. CrossRef.

   Rosenblatt AD (1988) Envy, identification, and pride. Psychoanalytic Quarterly LVII: 56–71

   Roskruge M, Grimes A, McCann P, Poot J (2013) Homeownership, social capital and satisfaction with local government. Urban Studies 18: 2517–2534. CrossRef.

   Sengupta NK, Luyten N, Greaves LM, Osborne D, Robertson A, Armstrong G, Sibley C (2013) Sense of community in New Zealand neighbourhoods: a multi-level model predicting social capital. New Zealand Journal of Psychology 42: 36–45

   Sevin HE (2014) Understanding cities through city brands: city branding as a social and semantic network. Cities 38: 47–56. CrossRef.

   Smith TW, Kim S (2006) National pride in comparative perspective: 1995/96 and 2003/04. International journal of public opinion research 18: 127–136. CrossRef.

   Stiglitz J, Sen A, Fitoussi J (2009) Report of the commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress. Commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress, Paris

   Subramanian SV, Jones K, Duncan C (2003) Multilevel methods for public health research. In: Kawachi I, Berkan LF (eds), Neighbourhoods and health. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 65–111. CrossRef.

   Sullivan G (2014a) Collective emotions, german national pride and the 2006 world cup. In: Sullivan G (ed), Understanding collective pride and group identity: new directions in emotion theory, research and practice. Routledge, New York

   Sullivan GB (2014b) Understanding collective pride and group identity: new directions in emotion theory, research and practice. Routledge, New York

   Sussmuth B, Heyne M, Maennig W (2010) Induced civic pride and integration. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 72: 202–220. CrossRef.

   Tajfel H, Turner JC (1979) An integrative theory of intergroup conflict. the social psychology of intergroup relations. In: S.Worchel WGA (ed), The social psychology of intergroup relations. Brooks/Cole, Monterery, CA, 33–47

   Tracy JL, Robins RW (2004) Show your pride: evidence for discrete emotion expression. Psychological Science 15: 194–200. CrossRef.

   Tracy JL, Robins RW (2007) Emerging insights into the nature and function of pride. Current directions in psychological science 16: 147–150. CrossRef.

   Trueman M, Klemm M, Giroud A (2004) Can a city communicate? Bradford as a corporate brand. Corporate communications: an international journal 9: 317–330. CrossRef.

   Tyler TR, Blader SL (2001) Identity and cooperative behaviour in groups. Group processes and intergroup relations 4: 207–226. CrossRef.

   von Scheve C, Ismer S (2013) Towards a theory of collective emotions. Emotion Review 5: 406–413. CrossRef.

   Waitt G (2001) The olympic spirit and civic boosterism: the Sydney 2000 Olympics. Tourism Geographies 3: 249–278. CrossRef.

   Wellington Regional Council (2011) Wellington Region Genuine Progress Index (GPI: 2001-2010). Technical report, Wellington Regional Council, Wellington

   Wilcox K, Kramer T, Sen S (2011) Indulgence or self control: a dual process model of the effect of incidental pride on indulgent choice. Journal of Consumer Research 38: 151–163. CrossRef.

   Williams G (1995) Prospecting for gold; Manchester’s city pride experience. Planning Practice and Research 10: 345–358. CrossRef.

   Wood EH (2006) Measuring the social impacts of local authority events: a pilot study of a civic pride scale. Internatiional Journal Nonprofit Voluntary Sector 11: 165–179. CrossRef.

   Zenker S, Rutter N (2014) Is satisfaction the key? the role of citizen satisfaction, place attachment and place brand attitude on positive citizenship behaviour. Cities 38: 11–17. CrossRef.

A Appendix: Level 1 variables

The survey questions asked are as follows. The underlined responses are coded 1, the rest as zero.

Health Q29:
In general how would you rate your health? Poor, fair, good, Very good, Excellent
Duration Q8:
How many years have you lived in this city? Less than 1, 1-2, 2-5, 5-10, 10 years or more
Community-sense Q37:
R2. I feel a sense of community with others in my local neighbourhood: Strongly agree, Disagree, Neither, Agree, Strongly Agree.
Owner Q57:
Who owns the residence you live in? You own this house/flat/apartment, You jointly own this house/flat/apartment with other people, a family trust owns this house/flat/apartment, parents/other family members or partner own this house/flat/apartment, a private landlord who is not related to you owns this…., a local authority or city councils owns…., Housing New Zealand owns ….. Other State landlord owns…
Employment Q24:
Which of the following best describes your current employment status? By employed I mean you undertake work for pay, profit or other income, or do any work in a family business without pay. Employed fulltime (for 30 or more hours per week), employed part time (for less than 30 hours per week), Not in paid employment and looking for work, not in paid employment and not looking for work (e.g. full-time parent, retired persons).
Enough Q35:
Which of the following best describes how well your total income meets your everyday needs for things such as accommodation, food, clothing and other necessities? Have more than enough money, enough money, just enough money, not enough money.
Minority Q1:
Can you please tell me which ethnic group or groups you belong to? European, Maori, Samoan (and other non-European).
SafeCC Q13:
R4: Now thinking about issues of crime and safety, using a four point scale ranging from very unsafe, a bit unsafe, fairly safe to very safe, please tell me how safe or unsafe you would feel in the following situations. In your city centre during the day.
No rubbish Q17:
R1.. Have any of the following been a problem in your city over the last twelve months? Rubbish or little lying on the streets: yes, no, don’t know.
Conf_council Q21r3:
Thinking about your local City or District Council. On a scale of one to five, where one is strongly disagree and [four is agree] and five is strongly agree, how would you rate the following: R3. Overall, I have confidence that the council makes decisions that are in the best interests of my city or district.

Source: Quality of Life Team, 2009